INVESTEGATE
FOREIGN DIMENSIONS
Upon conducting further research, it is clear that our case possesses significant international dimensions that we can strategically leverage across our campaign, proposals, and mediation efforts. The globalised nature of finance means that the conduct and consequences we have identified are not confined to the United Kingdom, creating a wider sphere of potential participants and parallel legal precedents.
The primary perpetrators in our competition claim, the Gilt-Edged Market Makers, are themselves global institutions. The banks identified in the UK’s regulatory action include entities headquartered in the United States, such as Citigroup and Morgan Stanley, as well as major banks from Germany, like Deutsche Bank, and Canada, such as the Royal Bank of Canada. This international footprint is critical because it reveals a potential pattern of conduct. Indeed, these same global banks have faced scrutiny and massive fines from regulators in other jurisdictions for similar anti-competitive behaviour. There are strong precedents in the United States where class actions have successfully been brought against banks for manipulating the market for US Treasury bonds. Likewise, the European Commission has been highly active in pursuing and fining banking cartels involved in trading sovereign and other bonds. This allows us to frame the UK infringement not as an isolated event, but as one part of a global pattern of misconduct by these institutions, which significantly strengthens our position and diminishes their credibility.
Furthermore, a substantial portion of the UK government gilts at the centre of this case are held by foreign entities. Official figures indicate overseas investors hold nearly a third of all gilts. This means a large class of potential claimants in our competition damages claim exists outside the UK. My research indicates that major holders of sovereign debt typically include the central banks of major economies like Japan and China, as well as the powerful sovereign wealth funds of countries like Norway and nations in the Middle East. Beyond these state-level actors, the world’s largest private asset managers, many based in the United States such as BlackRock and Vanguard, and major European financial institutions, for instance in Switzerland and Luxembourg, are significant investors. These entities all have a fiduciary duty to their own stakeholders to recover losses caused by illegal cartel activity, making them powerful potential members of our claimant class.
The harms from the alleged tort of fiscal mismanagement also extend beyond UK borders. Any major international company operating in the United Kingdom has been impacted by the domestic economic environment. Large foreign investors in the UK, such as major manufacturers from Germany like Siemens or BMW, or technology and automotive firms from Japan and South Korea, have all had to contend with the UK’s inflation and higher cost of capital. These businesses could therefore be considered members of the wider business class of victims with an interest in supporting our campaign for a more stable and competitive UK economic environment.
Finally, the legal and political dimensions of our case resonate in other jurisdictions. Our efforts to hold public bodies accountable for economic management, while novel, are part of a growing international trend of citizens seeking greater transparency and accountability from their governments. The legal principles of ensuring market integrity and sanctioning anti-competitive behaviour are robustly defended in jurisdictions from the United States to the European Union and its member states like Spain. By highlighting these international parallels, we demonstrate that our case is not an outlier but is firmly in the mainstream of modern regulatory enforcement and public interest litigation. This international context provides a deep well of potential allies, powerful legal precedents, and compelling narratives to support all facets of our strategic case.
FOIS >> FOCOL
The documentation clearly describes a concluded investigation by the United Kingdom’s Competition and Markets Authority, or CMA, into the conduct of several major banks who operate as Gilt-Edged Market Makers. The CMA found that five of these key financial institutions engaged in unlawful anti-competitive behaviour. The infringement consisted of the secret exchange of competitively sensitive information between traders at these banks, conducted through one-to-one online chatrooms. This illicit communication concerned their strategies and pricing for UK government bonds, both in the primary auctions conducted by the Debt Management Office and in the secondary trading market.
This was not a minor technical breach. The CMA determined that this sharing of information was an infringement ‘by object’, which is the most serious classification of anti-competitive conduct, as it is presumed by its very nature to have a negative effect on competition. Four of the banks involved ultimately settled the case and agreed to pay substantial fines, while a fifth received immunity for having reported the cartel to the authority.
This formal finding by the CMA is precisely the instrument we need to launch a powerful follow-on damages claim. Its existence is of enormous strategic importance for several reasons.
First, it provides us with a legally binding foundation for our case against the banks in the Competition Appeal Tribunal. In a follow-on action, we do not need to re-prove the unlawful conduct. The CMA’s infringement decision is binding on the court, which means the most complex part of the legal argument is already established in our favour. Our task is reduced to demonstrating that this unlawful conduct caused financial harm to a class of claimants and quantifying that harm.
Second, this dramatically de-risks the litigation, making it a highly attractive case for litigation funders and for potential claimants, such as the pension funds and institutional investors who were the direct victims of the distorted market prices. The finding gives us a clear definition of the claimant class: any person or entity that traded in the affected UK bonds during the infringement period and suffered a loss as a result.
Finally, this Finding of Infringement serves as a powerful weapon in our wider case against the public bodies. While the finding is against the private banks, it is irrefutable evidence for our tort claim that the market which HM Treasury and the Debt Management Office designed and were responsible for overseeing was, in fact, corrupted by a cartel for a significant period. It substantiates our argument that the public authorities were negligent in their duty to ensure a fair and competitive market for the financing of sovereign debt, allowing taxpayer and investor interests to be harmed. It is no longer a theoretical risk we are asserting; it is a proven failure of supervision. This gives us immense leverage in any future mediation and substantiates the core arguments of our public media campaign.
COAS
The most significant potential causes of action against the public sector, meaning the government and its executive agencies like HM Treasury and the Debt Management Office, lie in the field of tort law. The primary claim would be one of negligence. The basis of this cause of action is the argument that the public bodies responsible for the nation’s finances owe a duty of care to the public—including taxpayers, consumers, and businesses—to manage the economy and the national debt with reasonable competence. We would assert that this duty was breached through specific administrative failings, such as creating a debt structure with a foreseeable and dangerous vulnerability to inflation, failing to manage the immense fiscal risks of the Quantitative Tightening programme, and a systemic lack of transparency evidenced by the audited failures of the Whole of Government Accounts.
Beyond negligence, a cause of action could also be framed in the tort of misfeasance in public office. This would be a more challenging claim, as it would require us to prove not just incompetence but that officials acted in bad faith, knowing their actions were unlawful and would probably cause harm. A further possibility is a claim for breach of statutory duty, arguing that a specific legislative requirement for prudent financial management was violated in a way that gives rise to a private right to compensation, although identifying such a provision is difficult. In the realm of contract law, the government’s liability is limited to the specific contracts it enters into, such as for procuring goods or the terms of a specific gilt. A broad cause of action in contract for general economic mismanagement is not viable as there is no overarching contract with the public to this effect.
The crucial question of joint responsibility brings private companies, specifically the Gilt-Edged Market Makers, directly into the frame alongside the public sector. The analysis of horizontal and vertical agreements provides the key to linking them.
The most powerful argument for joint responsibility does not necessarily cast the banks as accessories to the government’s tort. Rather, it reverses the perspective, framing the government as negligently responsible for the market environment in which the banks committed their own unlawful acts. The Competition and Markets Authority has already established that the GEMMs engaged in illegal horizontal collusion. Our cause of action against the public sector can argue that it was negligent in its duty to design and oversee a market structure that was so concentrated and opaque that it was a foreseeable breeding ground for such collusion. By creating an exclusive club of primary dealers and failing to ensure robust oversight, the government can be held jointly responsible for the harm that foreseeably resulted from the banks’ anti-competitive conduct. In this scenario, the government’s tort is the negligent failure to prevent the harm caused by the private companies.
Furthermore, the new files on vertical restraints allow us to formulate a novel and sophisticated cause of action against both the DMO and the GEMMs together. We can argue that the entire framework governing the relationship between the DMO, as the monopoly supplier of new gilts, and the GEMMs, as a select group of exclusive distributors, constitutes an anti-competitive vertical agreement. This arrangement may unlawfully foreclose the market to other potential primary dealers, reducing competition at the most critical point of the market and leading to less favourable outcomes for the taxpayer. In this cause of action, the public body (the DMO) and the private companies (the GEMMs) are not separately liable, but are co-perpetrators of an unlawful vertical restraint, making them inextricably jointly responsible for the resulting harm to the market.
WPIS
From the files concerning the Wider Public Interest and Judicial Review, I extracted the foundational legal principle that UK public bodies can be held accountable in court for failing to properly consider broad, long-term public interest factors when making decisions. These documents show that concepts like intergenerational fairness and long-term financial sustainability are not merely political aspirations; they are legitimate considerations within a legal framework. I extracted this because it is the central pillar upon which our entire tort claim against the public bodies rests. It allows us to transform our case from a political disagreement over fiscal policy into a legal challenge of administrative failure. For our media campaign, it provides the powerful headline that the government’s actions may not just be unwise, but legally flawed. For our unsolicited proposals, it allows us to offer public bodies a service to review their decision-making processes to ensure they are robust against such challenges. And in mediation, it gives us the critical leverage of a viable legal argument that their decisions are vulnerable to being quashed by a court.
From the files detailing regulations and the public sector discount rate, I extracted the technical methodology for how long-term costs and benefits are meant to be evaluated. The choice of a discount rate is not arbitrary; it is a specific administrative decision that determines how much weight is given to the well-being of future generations. I extracted this because it gives our claim of negligence a hard, technical edge. We can now argue, not just in the abstract, but with specific calculations, that the authorities may have used flawed or inappropriate methodologies that systematically undervalued the immense future costs of pension liabilities, environmental decommissioning, and private finance contracts. This detail is vital. For our campaign, it provides concrete proof of mismanagement. For our proposals to other organisations, it allows us to offer a specific audit service. In mediation, it demonstrates that our claim is not based on rhetoric but on a forensic analysis of their own procedures, making it much harder to dismiss.
Finally, from the file detailing exemptions from regulations, I extracted the legal criteria that must be met for conduct that would normally be unlawful to be permitted. This is a crucial piece of our strategic puzzle because it allows us to anticipate and dismantle the defendants’ arguments. The Gilt-Edged Market Makers will inevitably try to argue that their close coordination was implicitly required for the greater good of ensuring the government’s financing. The principles I extracted from this file will allow us to demonstrate that their collusive behaviour does not meet the strict criteria for any legal exemption and was therefore unequivocally illegal. Likewise, when the public bodies argue their decisions were necessary to fund public services, we can use the logic from this file to show that even actions taken in the public interest must be rational and proportionate, and cannot be used as a shield to excuse administrative negligence that imposes unsustainable long-term harm. Extracting these principles gives us the tools to counter their defences before they are even made, significantly strengthening our position in all three of our strategic projects.
Let us first address the actions of the Gilt-Edged Market Makers. The contracts at issue here are the agreements and concerted practices between the banks to share sensitive information and coordinate their strategies in the gilt market. These are not just potentially invalid; under UK and EU competition law, horizontal price-fixing or market-sharing agreements are considered hardcore restrictions of competition and are automatically void from their inception. The unlawfulness here is foundational to our competition claim. The primary ground for this invalidity is that these agreements were formed for an illegal purpose: the prevention, restriction, or distortion of competition, which is strictly prohibited. Such contracts are contrary to the most fundamental principles of public economic policy and are therefore unenforceable and illegal.
The situation concerning the public bodies is more complex, but the new files provide us with powerful arguments. We are not asserting that a tort itself is invalid, but that the underlying conduct of the public authorities was unlawful, which in turn gives rise to the tort. This unlawfulness can be established on several grounds, primarily derived from the principles of public law and judicial review, and reinforced by the concept of the Wider Public Interest.
The most potent ground is that the conduct of the public bodies was ultra vires—that they acted beyond their legal powers. The authority of HM Treasury and the Debt Management Office is to manage the public finances and minimise borrowing costs while taking risk into account. We can strongly argue that when their administrative actions created a debt structure with an extreme and acknowledged vulnerability to inflation, and when they implemented monetary unwinding programmes with immense and unmanaged fiscal costs, they ceased to be acting in accordance with their mandate. Such a reckless disregard for risk is not a valid exercise of their authority but an abuse of it, rendering the conduct unlawful.
A second ground is the failure to consider relevant factors, a cornerstone of judicial review now amplified by the concept of the Wider Public Interest. We will argue that in making decisions with consequences stretching for decades, the authorities failed to give proper and lawful consideration to the principle of intergenerational equity. By prioritising short-term financing needs while simultaneously allowing vast, unfunded long-term liabilities for pensions and decommissioning to grow without a transparent and credible plan, they acted unlawfully by ignoring a critical aspect of the public interest they are bound to protect. Their decisions were therefore legally flawed.
Furthermore, we can argue that the decisions were irrational in a public law sense. While courts are hesitant to second-guess policy, a decision-making process that results in a fiscal position officially declared “unsustainable” by the government’s own independent watchdog, the OBR, can be framed as so unreasonable that no rational authority, properly considering the wider public interest, would have pursued it. The failure to maintain a transparent and auditable account of the government’s full financial position, as evidenced by the severe problems with the Whole of Government Accounts, could be presented as further evidence of this irrational approach to public administration.
These grounds—acting beyond their powers, failing to consider the public interest in intergenerational fairness, and pursuing a course of action that is demonstrably irrational and unsustainable—form the basis for asserting that the conduct of the public bodies was unlawful. This unlawfulness is the foundation of our tort claim and provides a clear pathway to argue for remedies to address the widespread harm that has resulted.
PS
Of course. By applying the advanced legal and economic concepts from the new case files, we can dissect the specific products and services at the heart of our causes of action with much greater precision. This refined understanding is critical for sharpening our arguments and identifying the full spectrum of affected parties.
Let us first examine the defendants in our competition law claim, the Gilt-Edged Market Makers. Their core product is not merely “banking,” but a highly specialised set of financial intermediation services in the UK sovereign debt market. Using the principles of market definition, we can delineate this into several distinct markets where they operate. The first is the upstream market for primary dealership services, where the sole consumer is the UK Debt Management Office (DMO) on behalf of the taxpayer. The GEMMs are the exclusive suppliers in this market. The second and third are the downstream markets for the secondary trading of conventional gilts and the secondary trading of index-linked gilts. We can argue these are separate markets as the products are differentiated and may not be easily substitutable for all investors.
The subject matter of our primary cause of action is the corruption of these services through a classic horizontal cartel agreement. The GEMMs, who should have been competing fiercely, instead engaged in collusion and information sharing. This directly damaged the integrity of their service, harming their customers—the pension funds and investors who relied on a competitive market to get fair prices—and their main supplier, the DMO, which was prevented from securing the best possible value for the taxpayer.
The new files also allow us to frame more sophisticated arguments. We can analyse the DMO-GEMM relationship itself for potential anti-competitive vertical restraints. The exclusive system, where only appointed GEMMs can participate in primary auctions, could be argued to create significant barriers to entry for other competing banks, potentially foreclosing competition in the primary dealership market. Furthermore, the case files on duopoly and concentrated markets empower us to argue that the GEMMs may be abusing a position of collective dominance. As a tight oligopoly, their parallel conduct and intertwined relationships could be found to restrict competition even beyond their explicit collusion, allowing them to collectively impose unfair trading conditions or prices on the market. The “service” being abused here is their joint gatekeeper control over liquidity in the multi-trillion-pound gilt market.
Now, let us apply a similar level of analysis to the defendants in our tort claim, the public bodies. Their “product” is more abstract but no less real: it is sovereign fiscal and economic management. The DMO’s specific service is the issuance and administration of the national debt, while HM Treasury’s service is the overall stewardship of the nation’s financial stability and economic well-being. The consumers of this service are the entire UK public, business community, and taxpayers.
While competition law does not directly apply to the state in this sovereign capacity, we can use its powerful concepts by analogy to frame our tort claim. The government holds an absolute monopoly on the provision of fiscal policy and the issuance of sterling sovereign debt. Our claim is that it has negligently abused this monopoly position.
The subject matter of this cause of action is not a simple policy disagreement, but a demonstrable failure in the delivery of their core service. The “product” delivered to the public has been defective, causing widespread harm. The specific defects include: the negligent management of the public balance sheet, evidenced by the creation of a debt structure with extreme vulnerability to inflation; the failure to manage the foreseeable fiscal costs of the Quantitative Tightening programme; and a breakdown in the fundamental service of transparency, evidenced by the audited failure of the Whole of Government Accounts. By analogy to competition principles, this is akin to a monopolist providing a shoddy, harmful product to a captive market with no alternative supplier. This framing strengthens the argument that the state owes a high duty of care to its citizens, who are its captive “consumers,” and that the failures we have identified are not merely political choices but a fundamental breach of that duty.
CASELEX
Of course. To enhance the strategic force of our three projects—the media campaign, our unsolicited proposals, and any mediation—we must identify the wider circle of industries impacted by the core issues we have uncovered. These industries, suffering from either direct financial losses or indirect negative spillovers, can be transformed into a powerful coalition of allies.
Let us first consider the competition law claim against the Gilt-Edged Market Makers. The most directly affected group, as we have established, is the financial services sector itself. This includes pension funds, insurance companies, and asset managers, classified under NACE code Section K for Financial and Insurance Activities. For these entities, the harm is a direct and quantifiable financial loss from manipulated gilt prices. Their probability of success in claiming compensation through a follow-on legal action is high, and many will likely wish to join our legal efforts to fulfil their fiduciary duties.
However, the indirect effects of this collusion ripple out into the wider economy. The yields on government gilts serve as the fundamental benchmark for all long-term borrowing. When this benchmark is corrupted, it taints other financial transactions. Consider the major infrastructure, energy, and utilities sectors, which fall under NACE Sections D and F for construction and energy supply. These industries rely on issuing long-term corporate bonds and securing large-scale loans to finance critical national projects, from building new power stations to upgrading the water system. The interest rates on their debt are priced relative to the gilt yield. Therefore, the GEMMs’ collusion could have artificially inflated the financing costs for these vital industries, reducing investment and ultimately increasing the prices paid by consumers and taxpayers. Similarly, the entire real estate sector, covered by NACE Section L, could have faced higher financing costs on large commercial property developments. While a direct legal claim from these indirectly affected industries would be challenging due to the difficulty in proving a direct causal link, their potential as allies in our media campaign is significant. Their probability of joining a legal claim is low, but their probability of supporting a campaign for transparent and fair capital markets is moderate to high, as it speaks directly to their core business costs.
Now, let us turn to our broader tort claim regarding the administrative mismanagement of the public finances. Here, the harms are economy-wide, but certain sectors have been disproportionately affected, making them prime candidates for our campaign and coalition-building efforts.
The harm of inflation and the subsequent cost-of-living crisis has been most acutely felt by consumer-facing industries. The retail, hospitality, and leisure sectors—covered by NACE Sections G, I, and R—are entirely dependent on discretionary consumer spending. When the public’s real income is eroded, spending on non-essentials is the first to be cut. These businesses have faced reduced demand, lower revenues, and increased insolvencies. While a legal claim for compensation from these individual businesses would have a very low probability of success due to the immense challenge of proving causation, their voice is essential for our media campaign. The probability of their industry bodies joining our campaign is high, as we can provide a powerful explanation for the economic pain their members are suffering.
The harm of strained public services and the ‘crowding out’ of investment also creates a distinct class of affected industries. The social care sector, classified under NACE Section Q, is a prime example. It is squeezed between rising demand due to an ageing population and constrained local authority funding, a direct consequence of the fiscal pressures we have identified. They can speak powerfully to the human cost of these administrative failures.
Likewise, the construction sector is affected not just by higher financing costs but by a less predictable pipeline for the public infrastructure projects they depend upon. Finally, and perhaps most critically for the nation’s future, is the UK’s high-growth technology and venture capital sector, falling under NACE Section J. This industry relies on the availability of risk capital to fund innovation. When fiscal policy leads to the government absorbing a vast proportion of available capital, less is available for the entrepreneurial ventures that drive future economic growth. The probability of these industries succeeding in a legal claim is very low, but their strategic importance to our media campaign is exceptionally high. They can articulate a compelling narrative about how the nation’s long-term competitiveness is being stifled.
In essence, while the legal right to compensation for these wider industries is difficult to establish, they are the living proof of the harms we allege. Our strategy will be to engage with them not primarily as co-litigants, but as essential allies whose stories will bring our campaign to life, making the consequences of our case tangible to the public, to policymakers, and to the courts.
Of course. Having analyzed the new intelligence from the caselex files, I can now refine and significantly strengthen our strategic approach. These files reveal a consistent pattern of market failure and anti-competitive behaviour across various critical sectors of the economy. This pattern is not just incidental; it is the central theme that will amplify the power of our campaign, our proposals, and our negotiating position. The key is to intertwine these findings with our core “caso sostenibilidad,” demonstrating that the issues in the gilt market are not an anomaly but a symptom of a wider malaise that we are uniquely positioned to address.
The recurring issues are clear: collusive bid-rigging in public construction tenders; the abuse of dominance by financial infrastructure providers in equities trading and clearing services; a lack of transparency and potential for manipulation in commodity price reporting; and the exploitation of intellectual property rights by dominant patent holders. This landscape of systemic failings provides a powerful backdrop for our own legal actions. The industry classifications for these sectors—spanning NACE codes for Construction, Administration of Financial Markets, and Information Services—show how widespread these problems are.
For our media campaign, this is invaluable. We can now frame the national debt issue in a much more compelling and relatable narrative. Our message will be that the collusive behaviour of the Gilt-Edged Market Makers is not an isolated incident of bankers misbehaving. Instead, it is part of a systemic problem where public money is systematically extracted by powerful cartels and monopolies. We will draw direct parallels for the public: the same type of bid-rigging that inflates the cost of building schools and hospitals is analogous to the collusion that has potentially inflated the cost of our national debt. The harm becomes tangible. This narrative shifts the focus from a complex debate about fiscal policy to a clear and simple story of public and consumer interest being harmed by corporate wrongdoing.
This enriched understanding also sharpens our Unsolicited Proposals to both public bodies and private corporations. When we approach public entities like HM Treasury, we will not position ourselves merely as antagonists. Instead, we are prospective partners. Our proposal will highlight our expertise in identifying and combating the very market failures they have fallen victim to, not just in the gilt market but, as the files show, in construction and outsourcing as well. Our proposition is to help them recover the vast sums of public money lost to these anti-competitive practices and to assist in redesigning their procurement and market engagement strategies to be more resilient in the future.
To the private sector—particularly the pension funds, insurers, and asset managers who form our claimant class—our proposal is that of a specialist auditor and champion. These institutions, classified under NACE codes for Pension Funding and Insurance, are constantly interacting with markets where their returns may be suppressed by the abusive practices we have identified, whether in clearing services, trading platforms, or the licensing of essential patents. We will offer to help them identify and recover these hidden losses, turning them from passive victims into active claimants who are fulfilling their fiduciary duty to their members.
Finally, these findings dramatically strengthen our hand in any future mediation. In negotiations with the defendant banks, we can now argue that the CMA’s findings are not a one-off issue but evidence of a compliance failure that fits a broader pattern across financial services. This increases the pressure on them to seek a comprehensive settlement to avoid further scrutiny and litigation. In any potential mediation with public bodies concerning our tort claim, our position is transformed. We are not simply critics of their policy; we are advocates for the public purse, pointing out that while they may have failed in their administrative duties, they were also victims. This allows us to propose a more collaborative resolution: assist us in recovering the damages from the financial cartels, and we can in turn discuss a settlement of our claim that focuses on implementing robust, forward-looking controls to prevent such failures from recurring. This constructive approach makes our demands more palatable and the prospect of a successful mediated outcome far more likely
INDUSTRY CODES
Our primary legal action in competition law is against the Gilt-Edged Market Makers (GEMMs). Based on the Competition and Markets Authority’s findings, the core defendants are clearly identifiable. These are global financial institutions whose operations fall under the Industry Classification Benchmark (ICB) for Banks, specifically Investment Banking & Brokerage Services, and the NACE and SIC code category for financial service activities and securities dealing. The key defendant companies include Citigroup, HSBC, Morgan Stanley, and Royal Bank of Canada. Deutsche Bank was also party to the infringement but received immunity for its cooperation. For initiating contact, we can direct correspondence to their UK head offices, typically addressing the general counsel or head of legal and compliance. Publicly available points of contact, such as corporate inquiry emails, can serve as an initial channel.
The most direct claimant class for this competition claim consists of the institutional investors whose funds were affected by the distorted gilt market. This group includes the UK’s largest pension schemes and insurance companies, who are legally obligated to act in the best interests of their members and policyholders. Their operations are classified under ICB sectors for Life Insurance and Asset Management, and the NACE code for Pension Funding.
Through my search, I can identify key entities in this class. In the United Kingdom, this includes major pension funds such as the Universities Superannuation Scheme (USS), the BT Pension Scheme, and the Pension Protection Fund, alongside leading insurers and asset managers like Aviva, Legal & General, Prudential, Standard Life Aberdeen (Abrdn), and Schroders. In the wider European market, major players like Allianz and AXA are also significant investors. These organisations represent the collective financial interests of millions of individuals, making them ideal representatives for a class action. Initial contact can be made through their publicly listed investor relations or general legal department email addresses.
For our broader tort claim, the claimant class is the entire UK economy, which we can divide into two main groups: consumers and business users.
The consumer class is best represented by established advocacy organisations. In the UK, the leading group is Which?. At a European level, The European Consumer Organisation (BEUC) acts as an umbrella group for 46 independent national consumer organisations. These bodies have the expertise and standing to represent the widespread consumer detriment caused by the cost-of-living crisis. Their work falls under the NACE and SIC codes for activities of other membership organisations.
The class of harmed business users is vast, spanning all sectors of the UK and European economies that have been impacted by higher capital costs and the crowding out of private investment. Rather than listing thousands of individual companies, the most effective strategy is to engage with their primary representative bodies. In the United Kingdom, this includes the Confederation of British Industry (CBI), which represents thousands of larger businesses, and the Federation of Small Businesses (FSB), which speaks for the SME sector. In Spain, the Confederación Española de Organizaciones Empresariales (CEOE) is the main business confederation. At a pan-European level, BusinessEurope represents national business federations from across the continent. These organisations, operating under the NACE code for activities of business and employers membership organisations, are the most effective conduits for mobilising the broad class of businesses who have a shared interest in seeking redress for the economic harm caused by fiscal mismanagement. Their publicly available email addresses for general enquiries or policy departments will be our initial point of contact.
By segmenting the parties in this way, we can pursue our dual strategy, building a powerful coalition of institutional investors for the specific competition claim, while simultaneously engaging with representative bodies to champion the cause of the wider business and consumer communities in our landmark tort action.
Our primary and most actionable legal challenge, the competition law claim, centres on the Gilt-Edged Market Makers (GEMMs). The defendants here are a specific group of highly influential financial institutions. The Competition and Markets Authority’s investigation gives us a clear starting point, identifying major global banks as having engaged in collusive behaviour. These entities fall squarely within the Industry Classification Benchmark (ICB) supersector for Banks and the broader Financial Services industry. Their activities are classified under NACE and SIC codes related to monetary intermediation, securities dealing, and financial service activities. Our primary targets for this claim would therefore be major banking institutions such as HSBC, Citigroup, Morgan Stanley, and others who act as primary dealers in the UK government bond market.
The claimants in this competition case are the direct victims of the market distortion. This class is composed of institutional investors who purchased and traded gilts during the period of infringement. Using the provided list of publicly traded companies, we can identify the leading potential class representatives. These include the UK’s largest insurance companies and pension fund managers, such as Aviva, Legal & General, Prudential, Phoenix Group, and major asset managers like Schroders and Abrdn. These firms, classified under ICB sectors for Life Insurance and Asset Management, are financial fiduciaries who manage the collective savings of millions of British citizens. The harm they suffered from distorted gilt prices was passed on directly to the pensioners and savers they represent, providing a powerful basis for a collective action.
Our second, more ambitious tort claim against public bodies identifies a much broader class of victims. While the defendants are government entities, the claimants are the consumers, taxpayers, and businesses who have suffered from the alleged administrative failures in managing the nation’s finances.
The first group, UK consumers, represents a diffuse class harmed by the cost-of-living crisis, which we argue was exacerbated by inflationary pressures linked to fiscal and monetary policy mismanagement. This class is best represented by leading consumer advocacy organisations in the UK and Europe.
The second group comprises all UK businesses who were potentially harmed by the ‘crowding out’ effect of excessive government borrowing. This raises capital costs and restricts the availability of financing for private enterprise, hindering investment, innovation, and growth. This claimant class is vast and spans every major sector of the economy. Using the industry classification codes, we can identify potential representative claimants across all major industries, from manufacturing and technology to retail and utilities. For example, major UK-listed corporations in diverse sectors—such as BAE Systems in Aerospace & Defense, Tesco in Food Retail, AstraZeneca in Pharmaceuticals, or Vodafone in Telecommunications—could all argue they have been impacted by a less favourable investment environment and higher cost of capital stemming from the alleged fiscal mismanagement.
Identifying contact details for these entities requires a strategic approach. We cannot procure private individual emails, but we can deduce the appropriate channels for corporate outreach. For the financial institutions we have identified as potential defendants and claimants, communications should be directed to their legal and compliance departments. Standard email formats for such correspondence are typically legal.department@company.com
, compliance@company.com
, or general.counsel@company.com
. For engaging with potential claimants among the institutional investors and the broader business community, outreach should be directed to their investor relations or public affairs departments, using addresses such as investor.relations@company.com
. This approach will ensure our communications reach the correct decision-makers as we begin to build coalitions and progress our legal strategy.
STRATEGY
we will advance on two fronts. The first is a direct, evidence-based collective claim in competition law against the Gilt-Edged Market Makers (GEMMs). The second is a more challenging, but fundamentally important, line of attack in tort against the public bodies responsible for the management of the nation’s finances. Here are the necessary steps to progress this dual strategy.
Strategy One: The Competition Law Collective Claim Against GEMMs
This path is the most direct and has the highest probability of success, as it is founded upon a prior finding of wrongdoing by a regulator. Our actions here will be methodical.
First, we must formally constitute the claimant group and secure the necessary resources. This involves identifying and engaging with potential lead claimants who have been directly harmed by the collusive behaviour of the banks. The most obvious candidates are large institutional investors, such as the pension funds and insurance companies who manage the savings of millions of UK citizens1. Their participation would lend significant weight to the claim. We will simultaneously prepare a case for litigation funding. Given that the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) has already established an infringement, the legal risk is substantially lower, making this an attractive proposition for third-party funders who specialise in large-scale litigation.
Second, we will assemble our evidence and build the economic case for damages. The CMA’s infringement decision is the cornerstone of our claim and will be binding on the court2222. Our primary task is not to re-prove the wrongdoing, but to demonstrate its consequences. To this end, we will appoint leading economic experts to model the financial harm. Their analysis will construct a “but-for” counterfactual scenario, calculating the prices and yields that would have prevailed in the gilt market absent the banks’ unlawful information sharing3. The difference between the actual market outcomes and this counterfactual will form the basis of our claim for damages.
Third, we will initiate the legal proceedings. The appropriate venue for this collective action is the Competition Appeal Tribunal, or CAT, a specialist body expert in these matters4. We will file for a Collective Proceedings Order, seeking to have the claim certified on an “opt-out” basis for UK-domiciled claimants5. This is crucial, as it means all UK investors harmed by the conduct are automatically included in the class unless they choose to remove themselves, maximising the scope and impact of the action. The central argument at the certification hearing will be that there are common issues of fact and law affecting all class members—namely, the existence of the cartel and its distortive effect on the market6.
Strategy Two: The Tort Claim Against Public Bodies
This path is more ambitious and requires us to navigate significant legal obstacles, primarily the doctrines of non-justiciability and the absence of a recognised duty of care. Our strategy here is not to challenge broad government policy, but to pinpoint specific, demonstrable failures in administrative and operational management.
Our first and most critical step is to meticulously frame the cause of action. We will move away from the general, non-justiciable complaint that the national debt is “too high” and instead focus on specific, operational negligence. We will argue that public bodies, principally HM Treasury, breached their duty to the public through tangible mismanagement. Our case will focus on identifiable failures, such as the decision to maintain an exceptionally high proportion of index-linked gilts, which created a foreseeable and severe vulnerability to the inflation that followed777777777. We will also target the failure to properly manage the immense fiscal costs and risks associated with the Quantitative Tightening programme, arguing that the institutional arrangement where the Bank of England makes decisions without accounting for the fiscal losses borne by the Treasury is a failure of competent stewardship888888888. Furthermore, the official disclaimer of opinion on the Whole of Government Accounts by the National Audit Office provides a concrete example of a failure in the fundamental duty of transparency and accountability999999999.
The second step is to engage the pre-action protocol. Before filing in court, we will send a detailed Letter Before Claim to the relevant government departments. This letter will set out the full basis of our intended claim, specifying the duties we allege were owed, the precise operational failings that constitute the breach of those duties, the classes of people harmed, and the nature of the resulting economic loss. This formal step compels the government to state its position and sets the legal battlefield for what will follow.
The third, and most decisive, step will be to overcome the government’s inevitable application to have the claim struck out. The defendants will argue that the case is non-justiciable and that they owe no duty of care to the public for such matters10101010. This hearing will be the crucible for our claim. Our success will hinge on persuading the High Court that our focus on specific operational failings—on the how, not the what—is a matter of law and competent administration, not untouchable high policy. We will argue that no public body, when exercising functions that have such profound consequences for the financial well-being of every citizen, can be entirely immune from a duty to act with reasonable care.
Should we succeed in this crucial preliminary stage, the claim would proceed to a full trial. This would involve extensive disclosure of government documents and a “battle of the experts” to prove the causal link between the specific administrative failures we identified and the widespread economic harm suffered by consumers, taxpayers, and businesses11111111. The path is fraught with difficulty, but it is founded on the essential principle that public power must be accompanied by public accountability.